Global Insecurity: Restructuring Social Income

by Guy Standing

"The certainties of one age are the problems of the next."
Richard Tawney


  1. Introduction

  2.  

     

    The 20th century was the century of the labouring man. It was also the century when the working class scared rulers almost everywhere, was twice decimated by world conflagrations, trudged out in support of two competing socio-economic systems ostensibly dedicated to its interests, and ended the century by splintering in disarray. One cannot reconsider social policy and development without taking the history of labourism into account.

    There is another, classical way of looking at what has happened. Recalling Karl Polanyi�s The Great Transformation, and risking the appearance of functionalism in presenting the process in brief, industrial capitalism has evolved through eras of stability and eras of upheaval. An era of stability is when the economy is embedded in society, that is, when the state legitimises and facilitates mechanisms of redistribution. The distributive system, and the state regulations associated with it, gradually over decades lead to "rigidities", which choke economic dynamism. Then there is an era of upheaval, when the economy is disembedded from society, when new forms of production and work organisation spread, and new forms of inequality and insecurity emerge. After a while, those become so great that they threaten the sustainability of the economic system. At that point, if economic progress is to resume, the state acts to re-embed the economy by introducing new forms of redistribution and means of ensuring enough economic security for those near the bottom of society to ensure legitimacy and sustainability.

    With that imagery in mind, it is not too fanciful to see the 20th century as dominated by two labourist models by which states attempted to embed the economy -- state socialism and welfare state capitalism. Both, in different ways, made labour the fulcrum of their development strategy. In order to try to facilitate analysis of the challenge before us during "the second great transformation" (globalisation), this note briefly considers relevant characteristics of the welfare state development model, the factors that undermined it, and the subsequent contextual trends which, it is suggested, should shape a vision of distributive justice on which to build.
     
     

  3. The Era of Statutory Regulation

  4.  

     

    "Labour is not a commodity."
    ILO Philadelphia Declaration, 1944

    The essence of the two models that competed during the middle decades of the last century was that they promoted labour security at the cost of constraining liberty, albeit in different ways. Both were initially based on the needs and aspirations of labouring man. Under both communism and welfare state capitalism, Full Employment was seen as the major instrumental goal. Adherents of both models tried to export their model to developing countries. The most extreme version of labourism was the Soviet Constitution, which declared that "he who does not labour shall not eat." We need not dwell on the characteristics of the state socialism model here. Although there have been several variants, the welfare state had a rather similar orientation, often linking entitlement to state-provided social protection to current or past performance of labour or willingness to perform it.

    The essence of social and development policy in welfare state capitalism was the promotion of seven forms of labour security, summarised in Box 1.

    Labour market security � Adequate employment opportunities, through state- guaranteed full employment;

    Employment security � Protection against arbitrary dismissal, regulations on hiring and firing, imposition of costs on employers, etc.;

    Job security � A niche designated as an occupation or "career", plus tolerance of demarcation practices, barriers to skill dilution, craft boundaries, job qualifications, restrictive practices, craft unions, etc.;

    Work security � Protection against accidents and illness at work, through safety and health regulations, limits on working time, unsociable hours, night work for women, etc.;

    Skill reproduction security � Widespread opportunities to gain and retain skills, through apprenticeships, employment training, etc.;

    Income security � Protection of income through minimum wage machinery, wage indexation, comprehensive social security, progressive taxation, etc.;

    Representation security � Protection of collective voice in the labour market, through independent trade unions and employer associations incorporated economically and politically into the state, with the right to strike, etc.

    The economic, regulatory and social policies were intended to achieve progress on all these forms of security, and generally did so. The model, underpinned by Keynesian economics, was based on a set of premises. Technical change was expected to be steady and moderate, the production structure was expected to be stable or only changing slowly, with enough time for employers and workers to adjust, without major fluctuations in employment. The labour force was expected to be overwhelmingly in full-time, regular jobs, with men comprising the primary workforce. It was presumed that the economy of any country was essentially closed, in that trade was either a small part of the economy or where it was not mainly involved trade in competitive goods conducted between countries with similar labour rights, and trade in complementary goods according to an international division of labour in which developing countries mainly exported primary goods. The model implicitly depended on dividing the global economy into "three worlds" � industrialised, communist and the Third World � with a static international division of labour.

    The regulatory framework was predominantly pro-collective and based on a mix of statutory regulations, epitomised by increasingly complex and comprehensive laws and procedures, coupled with voice regulation, exercised by legitimised trades unions and employer organisations, protected by measures to extend freedom of association, often backed up by neo-corporatist "tripartite" mechanisms. Because the system relied primarily on laws and regulations, one might call the period from about 1945 to 1975 the era of statutory regulation.

    There was a rough distributional quid pro quo, in which, in return for leaving the managerial right to manage virtually intact, there was to be �redistribution from growth�, gradually shifting income in favour of workers and lower-income groups. Workers and unions struggled for what amounted to the "decommodification of labour", through raising the social income -- not just raising money wages but shifting a growing share of remuneration onto enterprise and state benefits, as well as giving workers� implicit income in the form of labour protection. This was the focus of the distributional struggle. There was never a distributional consensus, because unions and workers always pushed for a more rapid improvement in social income while employers tried to arrest that process. It was the employers who made most of the concessions.
     
     

  5. The Era of Market Regulation

  6.  

     

    In the 1970s, while state socialism was easing into stagnation that brought it to collapse, the institutional arrangements of welfare state capitalism began to unravel. The model was eroded by several factors, which included:

     
  1. Contextual Outcomes: Globalisation, Informalisation and Flexibility
"The rapid advance towards the globalisation of economic and financial systems also illustrates the urgent need to establish who is responsible for guaranteeing the global common good and the exercise of economic and social rights.  The free market by itself cannot do it, because in fact there are many human needs that have no place in the market�We urgently need a new vision of global progress in solidarity, which will�enable all people to realise their potential."

-- The Pope, December 1998.

Among the outcomes of the era of market regulation to keep in mind is the evidence that poverty and inequality have increased in much of the world. But there are a few other contextual trends that may be highlighted for our purposes.

We may as well begin with "globalisation". This has come to mean greater openness of national economies, in which capital mobility has increased (size, volatility, speed and, perhaps most importantly, potential mobility), in which national economic and social policy has been more constrained by international pressures, and in which the balance of bargaining strength has shifted from �labour� to �capital�. Globalisation is seen as threatening the viability of certain forms of welfare state and regulatory system, and has contributed -- to a smaller or greater degree according to one�s perception � to the growth of economic inequality and labour insecurity. This may be a reasonable assessment, although there are still sceptics. But there is one sense that must be resisted � globalisation has been used by some commentators to tell proponents of redistributive policies that there is no choice, except to adapt and to accept permanently greater inequality.

Linked to globalisation has been the global technological revolution, the most relevant points of which are:

  • Decentralisation and multi-site production is more feasible than when �heavy� technology predominated ;
  • More managerial options in the way firms can organise labour arrangements, payment systems, and so on;
  • The labour market, organization and technological changes have facilitated the feminisation of employment.
  • New technologies, combined with globalisation, have contributed to the global growth of flexible systems of production and flexible labour markets.
  • The growth of flexible labour systems has been pervasive. One can identify seven main forms, which give a context for assessing mechanisms of social protection and security:
  • Organisational flexibility � more turnover of firms, more use of sub-contracting and production �chains�, and a tendency to contract the employment function;
  • Numerical flexibility � more use of external labour, such as contract workers, outworkers, homeworkers, agency labour, temporary workers, and teleworkers;
  • Functional flexibility � greater change in work tasks, job rotation, and skill;
  • Job structure flexibility � more changes of restructuring jobs and occupational structures in production;
  • Working time flexibility � more continuous working, flexible hours, etc.;
  • Wage system flexibility � a shift from fixed to flexible wages, monetisation of remuneration, greater use of bonuses, etc.;
  • Labour force flexibility � less attachment to sectors, companies or occupational groups, erosion of �collective labour�, and greater tendency for workers to move in and out of the labour market and labour force.
  • These trends have contributed to the global informalisation of economic activity. One must be careful about the term "informalisation" and even more so with the term "informal sector", which is associated with the ILO. It may seem a digression to emphasise reasons for disquiet. But the phenomena are too disparate to be compressed into a single notion. One should distinguish between something like the following four groups: It is conceptually important to distinguish between such groups, because their needs and insecurities differ, and because the type of social protection policy appropriate for them are likely to differ very considerably.

    What is clear is that the labour market presumptions that underlay the labourist models of the 20th century have been shown to be invalid. It had long been anticipated that the vast majority of workers would be in stable, full-time wage employment, able to pay insurance contributions or have them paid for them, in order to give them social protection against the "temporary interruptions in earnings power". In developing countries, it was expected that gradually that model would emerge, as surplus labour was absorbed into the "modern" or "formal" sector. In a few countries that has happened to some extent, but mainly it has not, and there is no prospect that it will do so in the near or medium-term future. Not only are �modern� firms not resorting to the standard employment model, but the state sector that was expected to be, and for a long time was, a major source of �formal� employment has been shrinking or stagnant in much of the world. And in industrialised countries, there has been a trend away from standard, regular, protected full-time employment, such that now in some countries only a minority of the employed is in such jobs.

    A final contextual point is that the intellectual changes that shaped economic, social and labour market policy in the 1980s and 1990s may be running out of steam. A feature of recent years, culminating in the imagery of globalisation, is that for the first time in history we have been offered a model of economic and social development that is supposed to apply to all countries. In the 19th century, and for part of the 20th, colonial powers divided countries into �civilised� and �uncivilised�, with the �natives� expected to provide primary goods. Later �under-developed countries� were expected to pursue policies of import-substitution industrialisation. Then there was the era in which the two labourist models were presented as alternative models for developing countries to adopt, usually under external tutorage. But since the 1980s, the Chicago school � or, as it evolved, the Washington consensus � has been the only serious model on offer.

    One predicts that this hegemony will weaken, and it will do so precisely because the inequalities and insecurities are becoming too extensive and severe. There is no reason to agree with people like Sachs, who claimed the upheavals of 1997 were "the end of an era". However, the disembeddedness of the economic system may have become so excessive that it is threatening the stability of national economies and the process of globalisation.

    For two decades, the Chicago school of law and economics and libertarianism combined to shape mainstream thinking, but in the late 1990s their advocates� confidence was shaken. Here is some good news. The World Bank�s Chief Economist, Jo Stiglitz, resigned at the end of 1999, having said that the Washington consensus is bunk and wrong. He deserves to be saluted. There is an awkward problem. For over two decades, the World Bank has devoted billions of dollars to induce countries all over the world to adopt the policies of that consensus. If there is an attempt to re-arrange "the financial architecture" (one of the latest euphemisms), it is not too cynical to predict that the restructuring will be devoted mainly to stabilising capital markets, not to addressing the social and distributional concerns of most people. For the ILO and UNRISD, a strategic question is whether we should engage in more open debate with the international financial agencies on principles of human security and on policies to promote it, and if so how that could be done.

    Beyond these minor internal considerations, it is perhaps symptomatic of the intellectual crisis that the cacophony that goes for international debate is replete with mischievous euphemisms. In most countries the package of policies that has been "globalised" has produced �stabilisation� without stability � epitomised by the periodic crises that break out somewhere in the world, such as Mexico in 1994, east Asia in 1997, Brazil in 1999, and Russia every six months. There has been "deregulation" that has involved many new regulations, and there have been �safety nets� without safety, as millions more people are pushed into poverty and as inequalities have grown. No wonder Stiglitz and others are worried. Whether any Bank is the appropriate institution to articulate or implement it, we may indeed need a "new development paradigm", one based on reducing insecurity and inequality, and re-embedding social policy in the economy.
     

    1. Labour Insecurity and "Social Safety Nets"
    If a mass of anecdotal and indirect evidence is to be believed, the era of market regulation has ushered in a period of more intense insecurity, and yet the statistical information with which most economists and commentators monitor economic and social change has failed to capture it. This applies to developing countries, �transition� countries and industrialised countries alike. In effect, as a modal trend, globalisation is involving "labour re-commodification". This reflects a reduction in support systems in low-income economies, cuts in non-wage income for many groups of workers, including erosion of forms of labour-related security, and a reduced prospect of receiving adequate social income for those on the edge of labour markets.

    Of course, the majority of people in the low-income countries of Africa, Asia and Latin America have long suffered from chronic economic insecurity � the slightest mishap could push many into an abyss. Yet we also know that a country�s income level is not the only factor that produces collective or individual insecurity. Labour and social relations of production and distribution play a major part in ensuring entitlements (long known before Sen�s study of famines), and the social structure will usually determine whether a community survives an economic or ecological shock.

    There are reasons for thinking that the fragility of security in low-income developing countries has been increased, because of the erosion of traditional kinship systems of social support, as well as by mass urbanisation and the economic restructuring. But all forms of labour security have been eroded around the world. Briefly:

    In short, we are in one of those eras of widespread insecurity. In particular, it is worth highlighting the growth of income insecurity, and the associated changes in social income and socio-economic fragmentation. Before doing so, recall two aspects of the policies prescribed and implemented under the aegis of the Washington consensus -- the social safety net and decentralised labour relations.

    On labour relations, decentralisation is part of a trend to employment and wage �bargains� made at the individual or small-unit level. Globalisation, with the shift in power and influence from the representatives of labour to capital, and with more labour flexibility, has contributed to this, and it is a global phenomenon. From the days of comprehensive �incomes policy� in the 1960s and 1970s, the vision of national-level tripartite bargaining has faded, only kept going in a few places such as the Netherlands, where the underlying rationale has been concession bargaining by unions.

    Sectoral bargaining has gone into decline, because of the ability of corporations to switch production more easily and to indulge in whipsaw bargaining, and because workers� allegiance to sectors is diminishing (and the location of firms in specific sectors has also become more flexible). On the workers� side, lack of sectoral identity partly reflects the decline in job security and employment security, as well as the plunging decline in representation security, measured by the share of workers belonging to trade unions. In most developing countries, any trend that had existed towards improvement has gone into reverse.

    Occupational bargaining has long been divisive, since Taylorism largely destroyed the base of craft unionism, while bodies to protect �professionals� have been mechanisms for guarding the incomes and privileges of the privileged. The growing sphere of bargaining is at the levels of enterprise and firm, and increasingly at the individual level of the worker and employer. A consequence is that company unions and the like have been boosted, which have been instrumental in intensifying labour market fragmentation. The weaker elements are less likely to be protected by collective voice, while firms are more able to splinter their workforces into groups with dissimilar benefits, social entitlements and social protection.

    The ongoing changes in the character of national systems of social protection are complex, but for our purposes the principal changes underpinning the mischievous euphemism of social safety nets are:

    The language of �targeting� on the needy has meant a global drift away from universal benefits, more means-testing, greater conditionality in determining entitlement to state benefits, lower "generosity" in the level of benefits provided, and shorter duration for entitlement to certain benefits. Unemployment insurance benefits may be in terminal decline. There has been a trend away from social insurance, both in terms of reforms of actual schemes and in terms of proportions of workers in statuses that gives them entitlement to them. Multi-tierism is spreading fast � such as a low level of state provision, a mandatory insurance-based second tier, an employment-based negotiated third tier and a private individual savings-based top tier. This has been most advanced in the sphere of pensions, but is spreading to other spheres, such as health services and schooling. Multi-tierism is linked to the partial privatisation of social protection, resulting in a cut in state coverage and in greater differentiation in access. A powerful lobby exists to extend privatisation as far as possible, and major multinational corporations are involved in this process.

    For our purposes, the main significance of these trends in the character of labour markets, labour relations and social protection is that they seem to be accentuating the fragmentation of societies into groups with sharply different opportunities and access to elements of social income.
     

    1. The Concept of Social Income

    2.  

       

      If we talk of a need for income security, we need a reasonable idea of what counts as income, as well as what counts as security. Does the following help? Would the proposed disaggregation facilitate analysis, policy consideration and data gathering?

      The suggestion is that we think in terms of social income. In any society, every individual has some source of income, or dies. The total may be inadequate or grotesquely large. There are various sources, and the composition determines not just the level but also the overall security of income.

      Basically, any individual in any society has up to five sources of income, which together constitute the person�s social income. This may be defined as follows:

      SI = W + CB + EB + SB + PB

      where SI is the individual�s total social income, W is the money wage or income received from work, CB is the value of benefits or support provided by the family, kin or the local community, EB is the amount of benefits provided by the enterprise in which the person might be working, SB is the value of state benefits provided, in terms of insurance benefits or other transfers, including subsidies paid to workers or through firms to them, and PB is private income benefits, gained through investment, including private social protection.

      We can disaggregate the elements as follows:

      SI = (Wb + Wf ) + (FT + LT) + (NWB + IB) + (C + IS + D) + PB

      where Wb is the base or fixed wage, Wf is the flexible part of the wage (bonuses, etc.), FT are family transfers, LT are local community transfers, including any income from charity, non-governmental organisations, etc., NWB are non-wage benefits provided by firms to their workers, IB are contingency, insurance-type benefits provided by firms to their workers, C are universal state benefits (citizenship rights), IS are insurance-based income transfers from the state in case of contingency needs, and D are discretionary, means-tested transfers from the state.

      We do not have data on the distribution of social income, or of the weights of the several components. However, based on anecdotal and scattered data, we can guesstimate the modal patterns in the regions of the world during the era of statutory regulation. In a stylised way, we can guess that relative to other regions and as a proportion of total personal income, in the post-1945 era the average values of the components of the social income, as expressed in the first identity, were as follows:

      Table 1: Relative Structures of Social Income in Era of Statutory Regulation, by Region

      W EB SB PB CB

      Africa Medium Low Low Low High

      Western Europe Medium Medium High Medium Low

      Eastern Europe Low High Low Low Low

      North America Medium Medium Low High Low

      Latin America Medium Low Low Medium Medium

      South Asia Low Medium Low Low Medium

      South-East Asia Low Medium Low Low High

      For example, in western Europe, for the average person the share of total social income accounted for by the money wage was about average for the world, whereas the share coming from state benefits was high by world standards and the share coming in the form of informal transfers from the local community was low. In eastern Europe, the money wage was a small part of social income, while enterprise benefits comprised a very high share. In east Asia, money wages were not only low in absolute terms but were a small share of social income, while community transfers comprised a high share � wage workers were subsidised by their predominantly rural kinship communities.

      When commentators said that "labour is not a commodity" and referred to "de-commodification" in the middle decades of the 20th century, they meant that a growing proportion of social income was coming from non-wage, non-monetary elements. By contrast, although one would have to document it, it is not too fanciful to depict recent trends as increasing "labour re-commodification", since for many groups in various ways there has been a shift away from non-wage, non-monetary forms of social income to money wages.

      Perhaps the most important ways have been the erosion in informal social support systems, particularly in developing and �transition� countries, and removal or loss of entitlement to enterprise and state benefits. But there are other ways too, often harder to evaluate. Suppose, to give an illustrative example, a man was receiving $100 as a wage, and had a long-term secure employment contract, guaranteed healthcare, subsidised canteen food and membership of a group pension scheme. The total value might be $200. How do we measure the value to the worker of the employment guarantee? One imagines many people would be prepared to sacrifice, say, 10% of their income to retain such a guarantee. If an employer takes the guarantee away and gives the worker a 10% pay rise, our statistics would show wages rising by 10%, which is misleading because all that has happened is that the structure of social income has changed.

      Although we do not have good data to demonstrate it, something like this seems to have been happening all over the world � except that for many there has been no compensation for loss of security or the hope that they could obtain it has diminished. Another example is where there is a shift from SB to PB, or a shift to IB in which workers have to pay a higher share of the costs to secure the benefit. In such cases, the cost might account for proportionately more of the social income of the low-paid, insecure worker, and the actual cost might be higher as well.

      In short, under the impact of economic liberalisation and "globalisation", the structure of social income has been changing. Overall, one may hypothesise that the median changes taking place in the designated regions are as in Table 2, where a plus sign implies a rise in the relative contribution to individual income, a minus sign implies the opposite. Where both a plus and a minus sign are given, one surmises that part of the growth of income differentiation is due to a shift in one direction for some groups and in the opposite for others. Table 2 suggests that in most parts of the world there has been a shift to money wages and a shrinkage in the share provided by state benefits and services. Perhaps most significantly � and this is a guesstimate rather than a statement based on substantial statistical information � there is increasing reliance on private provision (personal investment and saving) and community support (voluntary provision), or an increased need for those sources to fill voids opened by diminishing public provision.

      However, the disaggregation of Table 2 is not as revealing as when we consider what has been happening to the sub-components of social income and to distinctive socio-economic groups. Before considering this, we need to have an image of the labour fragmentation that has been taking place internationally.

      Table 2: Trends in Components of Social Income since 1970s, by Region

      W EB SB PB CB

      Africa -/+ -/+ - 0 0

      Western Europe +/- +/- - + +

      Eastern Europe + - +/- + +

      North America +/- +/- - + +

      Latin America + + - + +

      South Asia 0 ? - +? 0

      South-East Asia + + 0 + -
       
       

    3. Fragmentation: The Social Income under Strain

    4.  

       

      It is of limited use to consider social protection and human security as if there were no social groups or �classes�. Our conventional labour statistics are not very helpful. For instance, there are no peasants in international statistics. And we have no information on classifications based on the range of income sources and controls by which patterns of economic security or insecurity are reproduced or undermined.

      For our immediate purposes, we might find it useful to consider the following image of social fragmentation taking place internationally. The point of any such exercise is to identify groups that have distinctive sets of entitlements and patterns of social protection and security, and that are likely to have a particular attitude to various forms of social protection.

      A feature of the fragmentation is that growing numbers of people are detaching themselves or being detached from mainstream national regulatory and protective systems. It is presented in descending order based on average social income.

      * The elite. At the zenith of the globalising economy is an elite, consisting of a tiny minority of absurdly rich and high-earning people, whose impact is out of all proportion to their number. Some of these individuals have long since reached the stage of seeing their incomes rising almost exponentially. They are global citizens. Expanding the stratum down to multi-millionaires, the relevant points are that they are detached from national regulatory and social security systems, neither needing nor contributing to them, either psychologically -- not feeling committed to their maintenance or improvement -- or politically. The elite has very strong income security, and whatever they need of other forms of security. Their biggest danger is hubris, and being caught in criminality.

      * Proficians. These are the new craftsmen of the global flexible economy. As the name implies, they are a mix of professional and technician, mostly working as consultants or in short-term employment contracts. They operate in a climate of insecurity, but are well compensated for this. Perhaps their main form of insecurity is work insecurity, epitomised by the frenzied pace of their erratic work schedules, stress and burn-out. They are often able to evade or avoid taxation, and are at least partially detached from state-based social protection systems.

      * The salariat. This consists of salaried employees, including those working in civil services, large corporations, para-statials and other bureaucracies. They have a high degree of labour security, but probably suffer from some job and skill reproduction insecurity because they may be moved around and/or gain promotion in their enterprises by leaving technical skills behind them. Because of their reasonably high incomes and a tendency to identify with managements, employers and the elite and profician strata, members of the salariat typically feel detached from the state social protection system, seeing their future and income security in terms mainly of private insurance benefits and earnings from judicious investment.

      * Core workers. These are the bulwark of what those of us with long memories used to call the working class. Welfare states were created to serve the needs of core workers, those in full-time, regular, typically unionised jobs, usually with manual skills. During the era of statutory regulation, it was implicitly presumed that these workers represented the norm and that a majority of workers in all countries would eventually belong to this stratum. The larger the proportion of people belonging to it, the more people in a position to support and benefit from the mainstream, insurance-based social protection system and the mainstream regulatory system.

      The trouble is that although the legitimacy of a redistributive welfare state depended on core workers, they never comprised a majority of the economically active in most countries and since the 1970s have been shrinking. This is not just a reflection of "de-industrialisation" in industrialised countries, and the associated dispersion of manufacturing wage labour around the world. It is also because of various forms of labour market flexibility. Core workers traditionally benefited from most forms of labour security, but with the growth of wage system flexibility a growing proportion of their income has come in insecure form. They also suffer from increasing job insecurity and employment insecurity, while their unions have been weakened almost everywhere. Above all, with core workers dwindling in numbers and not expected to grow, their agenda has lacked legitimacy.

      * Flexiworkers. These comprise a disparate group of people in non-regular work statuses, including casual workers, outworkers, sub-contracted and contractor labour, agency workers and domestic workers. Their common characteristic is labour insecurity in almost all respects. In the era of statutory regulation and welfare state capitalism it was presumed that these "informal" forms of employment would decline as economies developed. In recent years, they have appeared to be the future. Not only have the number of people trapped in petty activities in rural and peri-urban areas grown, but the flexible labour processes have boosted many other forms. Among the associated trends, growing proportions of labour forces have lacked entitlement to mainstream statutory protection and have been disentitled to social transfers.

      * The unemployed. The number has risen extraordinarily in the era of market regulation. They suffer from labour market insecurity, given higher unemployment, and from greater income insecurity than in the past, because the level of benefits has been cut, duration of entitlement has been shortened, and conditions for entitlement have been tightened.

      * The detached. This is a growing minority of the population in many countries, cut off from mainstream state benefits, lingering in poverty, anomic and threatening those above them in the income spectrum simply because others fear falling into their ranks. In recent years, politicians have been inclined to treat these, many of whom are victims of economic liberalisation, as in need of "re-integration". They linger in the streets, in bus and train stations, in city parks. They make those above them in the social order feel uncomfortable or smug, depending on where they fit. The detached represent fear. And it is fear that induces concessions from the near poor � the ultimate tool of inequality.

      If one divides societies (and the international economy) into these seven fragments, one sees that the top three strata are increasingly detaching themselves from state-based social protection, while the bottom three are increasingly being detached by explicit and implicit disentitlement to its benefits and services. Although one may choose a different way of stratification, the analytical device may also help us to picture the growing inequality of social income and deterioration of economic security.

      Table 3 is an interpretation of what anecdotal evidence and reports suggest are the sources of income received by the separate strata, or the sources on which each group relies for survival. The asterisks indicate the main sources of income for the higher-income strata; the blanks imply that the source is not applicable, or that no guess on aggregate trend seems reasonable. The table�s final row indicates what seems to have been the global trend for the source of income specified by the column. Thus, the base wage has tended to decline as a part of social income, the flexible part of the wage has been rising, income from private savings and investment has been rising sharply, and so on. The +/- sign means the source has risen for higher-income groups, fallen for others.

      Table 3: Sources of Social Income, by Socio-Economic Status
       

      Sources
      Stratum
      Wb
      Wf
      FT
      LT
      NWB
      IB
      C
      Is
      D
      PB/K
      Elite                  
      ***
      Proficians  
      *
           
      +
      +
         
      *
      Salariat
      *
      +
         
      *
      *
      +
      +
       
      +
                           
      Core
      +
      +
         
      +
      +
      +
      +
         
      Flexiworkers  
      +
      +
      +
         
      +
      (+)
         
      Unemployed    
      +
      +
         
      +
      (+)
      +
       
      Detached      
      +
         
      +
       
      +
       
      Global trend
      +
       
      +
      +/�
      +/�
      +
      *

      Table 4 complements Table 3, in that it indicates how the seven strata experience various forms of security. Thus, for example, proficians have high levels of income security and skill reproduction security, being in control of their own activities, but no employment or job security. Core workers have some employment security (although diminishing), relatively high work security and reasonable entitlement to enterprise and other benefits.

      Table 4: Forms of Labour Security, by Socio-Economic Status
       

      Security 
      Stratum
      Labour market
      Employ-ment
      Job
      Work
      Skill Reprod.
      Income
      Benefits
      Represen-tation
      Elite
      +
      +
      +
      +
      +
      +
      +
      0
      Proficians
      (+)
      +
      +
      0
      Salariat
      +
      +
      (+)
      +
      (+)
      +
      +
      0
      Core
      0
      (+)
      0
      +
      0
      0
      +
      +
      Flexiworkers
      Unemployed
      Detached

      Note: +, above average; 0, average or not applicable; -, below average.

      Although one may quibble with Tables 3 and 4, they suggest a way of interpreting what is happening to income and income security. The socio-economic fragmentation has produced a situation in which those in -- or identifying with -- the top three strata feel increasingly detached from the mainstream state social protection system. They are thus less inclined to defend its principles of social solidarity, while the bottom three strata feel deprived, detached by disentitlement to the benefits long offered to core workers, to whose ranks they had aspired. To them, there is no solidarity on offer, and for them, to talk about social solidarity would sound like a sick joke. The pervasive detachment and lack of social solidarity have contributed to the loss of legitimation of the welfare state.

      An image of fragmentation coupled with the classifications of informal activities and forms of flexibility outlined earlier may be useful for assessing the relevance of policies to give social protection and security, and for assessing the limitations and apparent lack of general appeal of systems of social protection promoted in the 20th century.
       

    1. Welfare State "Crises"
    One might argue that reports of the welfare state crisis have been much exaggerated. Nevertheless, doubts about its longevity and reports of its morbidity have been persuasive. Although one might prefer to call them �dilemmas�, there are several types of crisis, which can be listed without much comment or justification.
      • "The deserving poor", to be offered a residual social safety net, through means-tested basic benefits (including basic first-tier pensions);
      • "The undeserving poor", offered the carrot and stick of �workfare� and/or conditional low-level transfers;
      • "The transgressing poor" (those who fail and resort to unsociable behaviour), offered the stern state prepared to uphold the law in keeping public order.
    Essentially, the moral dilemmas arise from a claim that there cannot be rights without obligations. This ill-defined "reciprocity principle" leads in the direction of direction, to the imposition of obligations to take jobs or �training places�, or to participate in �public works�, if people wish to receive state benefits. Is this justifiable? Is it equitable? Is there an optimum mix of liberty and security? There has been an international tendency to introduce new conditions determining entitlement to benefits and to apply old conditions more strictly. In effect, in terms of social income, there has been a trend from citizenship benefits to means-tested benefits, discretionary benefits and behaviour-tested benefits. Each time new tests, conditions or discretionary procedures are introduced, moral judgments are made.

    Other moral dilemmas deserve reflection as well. For example, as part of the partial privatisation of social protection, some governments have given tax incentives to encourage individuals and firms to donate money to charities, which in turn support some groups rather than others, decided by procedures that are rarely socially accountable or transparent. This sort of civil society issue will surely become more prominent soon.

    Another example is a selective transfer such as maternity leave. What is the moral justification for granting women in well-paid jobs paid maternity leave and benefits, while a woman living in a slum without a regular wage job is excluded? In most societies, the woman in a wage job would already have more income security than most of those without jobs. One can no doubt think of many other moral dilemmas that arise from the drift to selectivity and other reforms that have predominated in recent years.

    Among these are the famous moral hazards of selective social protection policy. The following come to mind:

    ** �Behavioural traps� -- a tendency to adapt behaviour so as to become eligible for a conditional benefit; this is the standard example, taken to ludicrous proportions as in the claim that young girls become pregnant so as to obtain �family benefits�.

    ** �Poverty� and �unemployment� traps � the standard cases where taking available jobs would result in losing so much in transfers that the incentive to take a job would be minimal.

    ** �Savings traps� � where means or assets tests are used to determine eligibility to state transfers, there is a disincentive to save.

    ** �Labour market traps� � a tendency to avoid actions that would be beneficial in labour market terms, induced by a policy design. For instance, the common condition that if a worker quits a job voluntarily he loses entitlement to unemployment benefits encourages some in low-productivity jobs to remain in them rather than quit to seek high-productivity jobs; a policy to deter �irresponsible� quitting ends up also deterring �responsible� quitting.

    It is probably fair to state that these and other distortionary or sub-optimal behavioural responses have proliferated with the drift towards selective �social safety net� systems, and that they will lead to more agonising over the desirable direction of reform.

    No doubt there are other aspects of the �crisis� of welfare states. Many stem from the gender debates and the need to make social protection and economic security more sensitive to the needs and working lives of women. However, as suggested above, other factors have contributed to the crisis, and it is hoped that the ILO�s Programme on Socio-Economic Security will help clarify some of the major themes that should be incorporated into the ILO�s future technical and advisory work.
     
    1. Selected Policy Options for Income Security

    "It is from the champions of the impossible
    rather than the slaves of the possible
    that evolution draws its creative force."

    -- Barbara Wootton

    The Programme just mentioned is exploring the advantages and disadvantages of a range of policy options proposed to extend basic social protection to groups excluded by conventional systems and to provide minimal income security for all, consistent with the commitment of all ILO member countries to these principles, as enshrined in the Universal Declaration of Human Rights and the International Covenant of Cultural, Social and Economic Rights. In doing so, it may be useful to consider each option in terms of the following evaluative questions:

    Without wishing to prejudge what should be on the long-term agenda, the following seem to be among the main options for improving income security, and in particular for extending protection to groups excluded or inadequately covered by mainstream systems and for providing minimal income security. In practice, packages of initiatives are required. In the reflections, it may be concluded that some options should be combined with others; some may seem undesirable, some to be subjected to public scrutiny precisely because they seem undesirable, yet are popular among policymakers. Some may be worth exploring through more systematic research. Some may be worth encouraging on an experimental basis. The Programme intends to produce a comprehensive compendium on several of the options for extending protection to the whole of society and for providing minimal income security.
     
    1. Concluding Points
    The world is faced by a short period in which two "new" models of development will be in competition. On the right, we have the libertarians and "compassionate conservatives" whose vision is still fairly clear, and whose influence on economic and social decision making is still pervasive, and will surely become more so under the Bush administration. They want a highly individualistic economy and society, with more constraints placed on collective bodies, and with privatisation of social policy to follow the privatisation of economic activity. They offer liberty without security.

    Recognising that something has to be done about the poor and the "losers" in the market economy, they offer a minimalist (residual) "social safety net" for "the deserving poor", which the state should provide through targeted, means-tested social assistance, coupled with fiscal and moral incentives to charitable disbursements from the wealthy. Faith-based organizations will be boosted everywhere, aided by foreign aid and much lusty rhetoric. For the "undeserving poor", they offer the carrot and stick of "workfare", "public works", and conditional, low-level state transfers. For the "transgressing poor", they offer a stern State prepared to uphold the law in keeping public order.

    On the left (if that is the right word), the rump of old �labourists� and social democrats are coalescing under a delightful euphemism � "Third Wayism". It seems to offer constrained labour market security with constrained liberty. It seems to lead to a more social, or moral ("responsible"), variant of libertarianism. It accepts and welcomes globalisation, in that it believes in economic liberalisation, low taxation on capital and on higher income groups, and a �need� for subsidies for capital. It favours some statutory protective regulation to strengthen labour rights, and believes that inequality can be redressed by raising employment and by increasing the "employability" of everybody.

    It too seems to divide the poor into the deserving-undeserving-transgressing categories. It advocates "welfare-to-work" schemes to integrate the victims of economic dynamism and labour market flexibility, tends to support wage and employment subsidies, tax credits, such as the EITC, and "welfare pluralism", in which social protection and social services are converted into "multi-tierism". Ultimately, Third Wayism is suffused with the �new paternalism� that guided US welfare reform in the mid-1990s, or the desire to have the state intervene to reduce "dependency", in deciding what is proper behaviour and what is improper.

    In the light of these conflicting yet overlapping models, and in the context of globalisation, perhaps we should reconsider what socio-economic security should entail in a Good Society of the 21st century. Of the seven forms of labour security, with more open economies and flexible labour markets (like them or not), labour market security is unlikely to return. In any case, one can argue that this particular form of security and employment security should be regarded as primarily instrumental, and by the nature of desired economic policy and labour market structure cannot be offered to all. While work, job and skill reproduction security are derived needs, for a society in which freedom to choose and to act and economic security are equally respected, the crucial forms are income security and representation security. Without basic income security, freedom to make choices and develop skills and a niche in society will be impossible. Without effective Voice, those on the margins of society, those vulnerable to impoverishing detachment, will be unable to overcome their marginalisation, and will be ignored in local and national policymaking, and in the expanding sphere of supra-national policymaking. Fragmentation and social dumping will become pervasive.

    The challenge before us is to find ways of giving Voice to all interest groups and to find ways of giving all such groups that minimal income security. The good news here is that there is growing intellectual and political unease at the morality, legitimacy and sustainability of the individualistic, disembedded winner-takes-all economy. Perhaps the ILO can reposition itself to turn that good news into a strategy for promoting new forms of security and distribution appropriate for the emerging global economic system. It might be worth the effort to try to do so. In the new century, Richard Tawney�s aphorism cited at the outset of this paper seems peculiarly apt.

    I would like to conclude with a statement of sentiment that seems even more apt for a conference with a strong gender orientation. It is taken from a dull paper that I have recently written about modes of control and the ILO�s "decent work" agenda. The theme is developed at length in a recently completed book on modern state paternalism.

    "Paternalistic control must be overcome as part of an agenda for occupational security. In doing so, how can a balance be achieved between freedom as autonomy and freedom as responsibility? The anti-paternalist believes in freedom from controls and freedom to be able to make rational choices � "the wish to be self-directed and not to be directed by others". But freedom is not unbridled individualism. Any individual needs some constraints � boundaries or pressures to direct him or her away from pure egotism. The desirable constraint is some form of collective that limits opportunism while facilitating the freedom to develop. This is the Voice security that we should be seeking.

    The trouble is that any collective by itself will become oppressive unless checked by some other form of collective. Thus, the family will be oppressive unless its members can draw strength from belonging to a wider community; the union will be oppressive unless civic associations can give strength to individuals; the civil society organisation will become oppressive and opportunistic unless its members can identify with a balancing group, and so on. We need a set of collectives. As noted earlier, G.D.H.Cole put it well in 1920, at a time of ferment as trade unions and cooperatives struggled for identity, "A person requires as many forms of representation as he has distinct organisable interests or points of view." In short, freedom requires a system of cooperative individualism in order to restrain moral and immoral hazards.

    This should lead us to consider current populist imagery. The notion of "empowerment" should be disquieting. We should feel uneasy about the language of battle. Of course, social relations are about adversarial bargaining and "struggle". It is intellectually reprehensible to talk or write as if there were no conflicts of interest; this leads to flabby thinking by bureaucratic minds unwilling to take intellectual risks. However, a danger of the current discourse around "development as freedom" is that it depicts freedom as competitive individualism, consumerism, possession, aggrandisement, maximisation of short-term profits and individual advantage. It fosters a Hobbesian mentality, which turns all social relations into "winners" and "losers". This freedom to be endlessly at war with our fellow beings, with nature and ourselves, is driving us into a frenzy of "competitiveness", egotism, stress, "labouraholism", "presenteeism", karoshi and other social sicknesses.

    Of course we need production, which requires incentives. However, we must reflect more. We need a softer tone, a less abrasive way of living, in which self-control does not mean merely freedom to compete opportunistically and frenetically with others more "equally". The stress that is the modern illness of the labour ethic will not be addressed by this route. We must reject the language of empowerment. It is "dis-empowerment" that is required; it is the negation of those controls, in order to liberate our enthusiasms, our creativity, and most of all, our capacity for contemplation and reflection. That is real security. The greatest freedom of all is to be still. Dignified work can only evolve if ordinary people have the capacity to say "No". This is a disturbing message for those who want to see the extension of markets to every crevice of human existence and who see the multiplication of jobs as the answer to the human condition. Dignified work needs basic security, or real freedom is denied. The ultimate paradox is that it requires the freedom to do no work at all. Dignified work can only exist when it is done for intrinsic reasons, not because a landlord, a boss or the State says it shall be so."